Japan
Revolution in the air
WHEN Shinzo Abe’s Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) won in a landslide
in December, the new prime minister promised leadership after years of
shambles. He pledged radical measures to snap Japan out of its long
economic funk and restore pride to a country nearly overwhelmed by a
sense of decline. On April 4th the man whom Mr Abe pushed forward as the
new central-bank governor, Haruhiko Kuroda, unveiled the first concrete
steps to suggest that Mr Abe means business. Mr Kuroda promised a “new
dimension in monetary easing” in order to rid Japan of the deflation
that has been its curse for more than 15 years. By Japanese standards,
Mr Kuroda’s measures amount to a revolution.
Thanks to deflation and low growth, in nominal terms Japan’s GDP is
no higher than it was in 1991. To have any chance of shaking the country
out of its deflationary psyche and of meeting Mr Abe’s call for an
inflation target of 2%, Mr Kuroda had to exceed already high
expectations. He did so handily. He said that the central bank would
expand its balance-sheet by the equivalent of over 1% of GDP a
month—twice the rate of America’s Federal Reserve. He promised to double
base money within two years. He also promised to double the central
bank’s holdings of government bonds. And he said that the new course
would continue for as long as necessary.
The prices of shares and government bonds have leapt, while the yen has slumped (see article).
That is all part of Mr Kuroda’s strategy. In particular, he promises to
hoover up longer-dated bonds and so bring their yield down; the central
bank plans to raise the average maturity of its bond holdings from
three to seven years. The hope is that private investors and banks now
shunning risk by owning government bonds will be forced to seek higher
yields elsewhere: either abroad (so weakening the currency) or by
investing in the real economy (so boosting demand).
It is a hugely bold experiment, with commensurate risks. If investors
came to worry that the Bank of Japan is too successful at raising
inflation they may dump Japanese bonds by enough to drive long-term
interest rates up sharply, an unlikely but dangerous development with
the national debt standing at 240% of GDP. Moreover, while deflation,
like inflation, is ultimately the remit of monetary policy, Mr Kuroda’s
cautious predecessors often pointed out that structural factors also
played a role: a declining population, suppressed domestic demand,
insufficient competition in many sectors and excessive hoarding of cash
by risk-averse companies.
Now it’s your turn, Mr Abe
Those problems remain, and Mr Abe must be absolutely clear that Mr
Kuroda’s boldness has to be met with even greater boldness on the
government’s part in freeing the economy. He should tackle head-on the
corporate sector’s excessive savings, for instance, by taxing retained
earnings that are not invested. He needs to do more to get more women
into the workforce. He must (against all his nationalist instincts)
promote immigration. He must open up protected sectors—electricity,
health care, farming—to competition. To that end, Mr Abe’s commitment to
join the market-opening Trans-Pacific Partnership is welcome. Yet the
fight with the farm lobby (see article), which has held the LDP in its palm, has barely begun.
A gauge will be how much Mr Abe capitalises on his high popular
ratings in the run-up to crucial upper-house elections in July to press
for change. His actions over the coming months will help to determine
whether he proves to be Japan’s saviour or—by promoting only a highly
unorthodox monetary experiment—its bane.
Nenhum comentário:
Postar um comentário